Ken Dobson's Queer Ruminations from Thailand
Search this site
  • Life in Thailand
  • Queer Issues in Thailand
  • Queer Christian Issues
  • Blog
  • Contact
  • Stories

Land

4/25/2015

4 Comments

 
Picture
Private land ownership in villages in Northern Thailand is precise, as it is throughout the country.  Every plot of land is owned by someone or else by the government.  A privately owned piece of real estate is described on a chanote tii din, a document which locates the plot exactly in relationship to landmarks, especially cement posts that have been planted by government survey teams working for the Land Bureau, a branch of the Agriculture Ministry. [See the picture above].  The copy of the chanote tii din, or real estate deed, in the land owner’s possession is one of two identical documents, the other one being kept in the local Land Bureau office along with the master record.

People living in a village usually have two types of land, one where their residence is and the other(s) which are farm land nearby.  A plot of land can be owned by any Thai citizen.  Family members can claim the right to have a say in the disposal of (sale or irreversible changes to) land they are in line to legally inherit.  Presumably this is to insure that no person can become landless against their will, but it seriously compromises the concept of land ownership.

As with all aspects of village culture, private land ownership can be divided into three historical phases: past, passing, and present (coming to be).  Also, as with other facets of village culture the transitions are slow.  That lassitude includes the phase that introduced private land ownership and the issuance of chanote tii din documents, the era now passing.

Before agricultural land was privately owned it was owned by the “Lords of the Land”, princes of the city states.  In our case here in the North the Lord was the head of the Lanna Principality (or kingdom).  The fact that people did not own their land hardly mattered in those days.  Traditions reigned.  Families knew which plots they farmed and that was recognized by everyone.  The irrigation system was maintained jointly.  Public works projects were done by conscripted labor, with most able-bodied males required to give 3 months a year to this.  There was no standing army, but those same men served if need arose.  Public land was mostly forests on hills.  Local people felt free to cut wood they needed.  The overall principle of the time was “subsistence living.”

 In 1901 King Chulalongkorn, Rama V, instituted the most significant long-range innovation of his revolutionary reign.  He mandated that people had the right to own the land they farmed and lived on.  The government set about regulating this land reform by surveying the country and marking it into plots – along traditional irrigation routes and field dikes. 

There are two ways to consider the King’s land reform.  First of all it was part of modernizing Siam, and not incidentally creating a vast new dimension to the economy.  Second, in a stroke, it deprived the traditional princes of their sources of power and wealth, which was key to centralizing power in Bangkok to counter threats of colonization by France and Great Britain.

Technically, this land reform was the end of serfdom, and the King emphasized it by ending slavery as well.  In many cases slavery was not what we think, but was forced movement of people for the benefit of different Lords of the Land, and in other cases a way of paying off debts through uncompensated work.  The movement of people also had a political aspect.  When one of the Lanna princes moved a community of paper craftsmen from Burma to Hang Dong District in Chiang Mai, they were technically slaves, but actually privileged by being exempt from taxes and labor conscription and were given prime land which displaced those who had been living there.  This resulted in social polarization in that community for well over two hundred years into the last quarter of the twentieth century.

Several major issues emerged right away, the biggest being: (1) how to manage new land that had not been farmed before, (2) and how to deal with land transfers and sales.  Integral to the land reforms was the desire to expand agriculture to be a major part of foreign trade and foreign exchange (which was, of course, a matter of governmental rather than local concern).  Rice and other products were needed as timber was running out.  This new agricultural expansion meant extending the irrigation system to service land at higher elevations and also deciding who was entitled to this new land being put into production.  In effect, the land was made available to those who would actually use it.

No single action in the past 200 years has had a more radical impact on the economic structure of Thailand or, ironically, has done more to concentrate power into the central elite.  Banks, owned by the elite (and in some cases creating new members of the elite), have replaced princes as the primary beneficiaries of agricultural systems of production.

It is an illusion that farmers own their land in actual fact, if (1) they must get government permission to sell or inherit it and cannot sell it to anyone who is not a full-fledged citizen, (2) they are dependent on water supplies controlled by the government, (3) they are unable to plant their crops without jeopardizing their titles to the land they farm (which they do when they borrow to purchase seed, fertilizer or chemicals), (4) they are unable to market their crops freely rather than through cartels controlled by the central elite at some point.  It is worth remarking that the less one in the chain of production has to do with the produce, the greater will be the profits; the farmer typically derives less than 15% profit from the investment, whereas the agency that purchases the produce makes at least 50% on their investment, the bankers who capitalize the middle-men make as much as 90% on their investment (considering their expenses, not their interest rate), and the government has a clear profit on any taxes and payments made to permit the banks and shippers to operate.

To summarize the first two eras: the first was characterized by subsistence living in which everybody in the village took care of themselves and provided service to the patron, the prince, for the protection and security they enjoyed.  The second era was characterized by the introduction of a money economy and the possibility of producing an excess of goods and services to provide for a level of living beyond subsistence.  Utensils and equipment were no longer made by hand or made locally, but were purchased for money.  Self-sufficiency came to an end.

The third era is the one unfolding before us.  This era has certain features of great impact.  (1) A middle class has expanded with someone in each farming family having a non-agricultural job, and each succeeding generation more dependent on salaried income. (2) The presumed dependability of salaries has had a positive effect on ability to secure credit and bank loans and to go into debt.  (3) As the largest profits go to those highest in the agricultural chain of production, incentives to work at lower levels diminishes.  (4) Village residency is no longer entirely hereditary, nor are village properties valued primarily as residences but also as ways to store wealth.  (5) Citizenship and land titles have become possible for most communities living on the hills as has long been the case for those living in the valleys.  (6) Means to do profitable hillside agriculture have become available as a result of leadership begun with Royal Projects.  (7) As the younger generation moves into the salaried middle class their intention to remain in the village goes down.  (8) As prosperity (including health and financial opportunities) increases, the average family size is reduced and the median age of village residents rises while traditional social security is weakened.  (9) It becomes harder and harder to sustain village projects with local voluntary contributions of time and money.  (10) To sustain local operations (including lanes, central water supplies, community organizations and village government) villages depend increasingly on outside support, usually from the central government, and village voices are unnecessary in decision-making.

All this because of land reform.

The only danger is that this economic system will collapse.  It is not an imminent danger, I hope.  But agricultural land values have escalated far beyond any possibility of agricultural returns on investments.  For example, we have 2 rai (.8 acre) of rice land next to our house which we bought 10 years ago for 300,000 baht.  Profits from each of 2 crops of rice a year is about 5000 baht.  It doesn’t take a genius to see we will never live to see the land pay for itself through rice farming.  But land values have risen in 10 years.  We could sell the land, we think, for a 200% profit, which is greater than any other real commodity we could have bought (as distinguished from paper – stocks and bonds), including gold which has only risen 120% in that time.  Just to be clear, the economic value of land in our village is exclusively what it will sell for.  That is not conducive to social stability.

To summarize the third era: the village is no longer the source of individual or family well being.  Almost all necessities are produced or manufactured away from the village and are purchased with money.  Land is the basic collateral for securing most loans that potentially exceed future earnings, and all loans, theoretically at least, have land at risk behind them.

4 Comments
CK Moore
4/25/2015 12:54:58 pm

thank you. It's very useful and informative.

Reply
Donald Johnson
4/25/2018 10:37:31 am

As our taxi driver said the other day, "the Thais buy the cars, the Chinese buy the land." The commodification of farm land and the fact that most Thai families are in debt up to their eyeballs, means that the percentage of landless farm workers has risen steady as rural Thai families have sold off or mortgaged their land at record rates. Average household debt now stands at around 200,000 Baht. I would estimate that farm workers who no longer own land stands at around 50 percent of the rural workforce. Many of these people are parttime farmers, and taxi drivers, factory workers, or grey economy workers when they aren't growing rice.
BTW, it is relatively easy for Chinese to obtain Thai citizenship, with the language requirement often waived for those with money, power, and connections. Thailand as a result will become a Chinese vassal state, like neighboring states such as Myanmar, Laos, and Cambodia already have. The urban elite has been Sino-Thai for generations, so it is easy for the Chinese to assimilate into this system.
I think the current farming system is unsustainable. Our food is poisoned by pesticides and the global petrol-chemical companies have debtbonded the remaining farm owners to heavy dependence on chemical fertilizers. Cancer rates will continue to rise.
The dispossesed will eventually become the majority, and without education their prospects for good paying employment become more and more bleak. This will lead to more calls for populist plans, such as rice price support subsidies. Discontent with the military regime will rise. Overall, the future for Thailand doesn't look rosy.

Reply
Kenneth Chester Dobson
4/25/2018 11:18:02 am

Although my essay is about village life as I can see it directly here in rural Chiang Mai, I cannot dispute any point you make, Don, as to the country at large. I think the poverty levels in Isan and the deep south lower the averages. Most land owners around here still own their land, but their children are going into debt at the earliest opportunities, using their ancestral land as collateral.

Reply
Anthony E Waters
3/14/2020 09:38:24 am

In the traditional world, land is not a commodity--cannot be bought and sold by those who farm it but can be used typical in a Thai Sakdina, or European feudal tradition. In the modern world, land becomes a commodity along with labor, capital, and commodity. Commodifying these factors is of course roughly done, and creates new kinds of poverty. In the end, people often end up dependent on the marketplace for food, and those left farming start making planting decisions (lumyai or rice?) based on the marketplace.

Reply



Leave a Reply.

    Author

    Rev. Dr. Kenneth Dobson posts his weekly reflections on this blog. 

    Archives

    December 2022
    November 2022
    October 2022
    September 2022
    August 2022
    July 2022
    June 2022
    May 2022
    April 2022
    March 2022
    February 2022
    January 2022
    December 2021
    November 2021
    October 2021
    September 2021
    August 2021
    July 2021
    June 2021
    May 2021
    April 2021
    March 2021
    February 2021
    January 2021
    December 2020
    November 2020
    October 2020
    September 2020
    August 2020
    July 2020
    June 2020
    May 2020
    April 2020
    March 2020
    February 2020
    January 2020
    December 2019
    November 2019
    October 2019
    September 2019
    August 2019
    July 2019
    June 2019
    May 2019
    April 2019
    March 2019
    February 2019
    January 2019
    December 2018
    November 2018
    October 2018
    September 2018
    August 2018
    July 2018
    June 2018
    May 2018
    April 2018
    March 2018
    February 2018
    January 2018
    December 2017
    November 2017
    October 2017
    September 2017
    August 2017
    July 2017
    June 2017
    May 2017
    April 2017
    March 2017
    February 2017
    January 2017
    December 2016
    November 2016
    October 2016
    September 2016
    August 2016
    July 2016
    June 2016
    May 2016
    April 2016
    March 2016
    February 2016
    January 2016
    December 2015
    November 2015
    October 2015
    September 2015
    August 2015
    July 2015
    June 2015
    May 2015
    April 2015
    March 2015
    February 2015
    January 2015
    December 2014
    November 2014
    October 2014
    September 2014
    August 2014
    July 2014
    June 2014
    May 2014
    April 2014
    March 2014
    February 2014
    January 2014
    December 2013
    November 2013
    October 2013
    September 2013
    August 2013
    July 2013
    June 2013
    May 2013
    April 2013
    March 2013
    February 2013
    January 2013
    December 2012
    November 2012

    Categories

    All

    RSS Feed

Copyright © 2023 Rev. Dr. Kenneth Dobson